Next Article in Journal
On-Site Experimental Study on Low-Temperature Deep Waste Heat Recovery of Actual Flue Gas from the Reformer of Hydrogen Production
Previous Article in Journal
The Agricultural Potential of a Region with Semi-Dry, Warm and Temperate Subhumid Climate Diversity through Agroecological Zoning
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Does Marketization Promote High-Quality Agricultural Development in China?

1
School of Economics, Shandong University of Finance and Economics, **an 250014, China
2
Department of Economics, University of Alberta, Edmonton, AB T6G 0B4, Canada
3
Faculty of Economics, Chiang Mai University, Chiang Mai 50200, Thailand
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(12), 9498; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15129498
Submission received: 7 May 2023 / Revised: 9 June 2023 / Accepted: 10 June 2023 / Published: 13 June 2023
(This article belongs to the Section Sustainable Agriculture)

Abstract

:
Over the past 40 years of reform and opening, the enhancement in marketization has greatly promoted the development of the Chinese economy. At present, China’s economic development model has shifted from a focus on speed to a focus on quality. Against this background, it is necessary to further promote marketization reform to promote high-quality development in China. This paper begins with an introduction to high-quality agricultural development and the degree of marketization. According to the definitions of high-quality development and marketization, we constructed an index of high-quality agricultural development and an index of marketization degree, respectively. First, we determined the characteristics of high-quality agricultural development in China. There are large regional differences in agriculture development, but these disparities are improving simultaneously, and regional differences are showing a narrowing trend, except for the western region. Then, we measured the impact of marketization reforms on high-quality agricultural development using the Quadratic Assignment Procedure. Based on sample data from 2009 to 2019, this paper found that marketization reform has played a significant role in promoting high-quality agricultural development. The three sub-indicators of non-state-owned economy, factor market, and the market’s level of order, which represent the marketization degree, had significant impacts on reducing regional differences in high-quality agricultural development. Additionally, the effects of these three variables gradually increased, narrowing the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development. Finally, we suggested that promoting the development of a non-state-owned economy, factor market, and the market’s level of order would be an important path to boosting the high-quality development of agriculture.

1. Introduction

Since the reform and opening, increased marketization has greatly improved economic growth. Given the high-speed development of China’s economy, it is worth considering whether further improvement in the degree of marketization can boost high-quality development of the economy. This paper uses high-quality agricultural development as an example to sort out the mechanism behind the marketization degree affecting high-quality agricultural development, explore and analyze the relationship between the marketization degree and high-quality agricultural development, and explain how the marketization degree promotes high-quality agricultural development.
Agricultural development is closely related to the level of economic development [1]. With the rapid development of the economy, China’s agricultural development has made great achievements. How these achievements were made is worth exploring. China created some subsidies to support agriculture, just like some developed countries have implemented the policy of supporting agriculture with industrial accumulation. The other develo** countries in Asia, such as Indonesia, the Philippines, and Vietnam, have also increased investment in agricultural support, including subsidies and insurance, promoting the industrialization and modernization of agriculture [2,3]. The government subsidies for agriculture in China increased from USD 450 million in 1995 to USD 65.5 billion in 2019; in Vietnam, from USD 100 million in 2000 to USD 400 million in 2019; in the Philippines, from USD 100 million in 2000 to USD 300 million in 2019, and in Indonesia, from USD 300 million in 1995 to USD 2.8 billion in 2019. In 2020, China spent USD 11.5 billion on agriculture insurance, becoming the largest investor in agriculture insurance in the world. Are these policies enough to support high-quality agricultural development? Many scholars have confirmed that China’s industrial structure optimization and industrial agglomeration have promoted the development of agriculture [4]. Based on the history of agricultural development in China, we found that marketization is another powerful force.
Marketization means the market plays a key role in resource allocation and means less government interference, which has greatly contributed to the economic growth of Chinese cities [5]. Since the opening and reform, marketization has become the fundamental driving force for the development of the urban economy. Gang et al. provided quantitative evidence that marketization contributed an average of 1.3 percentage points to China’s economic growth rate [6]. In 2017, the Chinese government announced an ambitious statement of high-quality development (HQD), which is an important guarantee for sustainable development. In general, HQD is efficient, fair, and sustainable development [7]. In this context, we are very interested in whether marketization has contributed to high-quality agricultural development in China.
High-quality agricultural development is a complex, systematic project. Agricultural development shows different characteristics at different stages of economic development. With increased marketization, China’s agricultural development displays the following characteristics. First, it has significant development potential. With the development of the market, agriculture-related service industries have been derived successively. These industries gradually become new elements that play a vital role in promoting the expansion of the agricultural production scale, optimizing the agricultural production modes, and more [8]. Second, the agricultural development mode is relatively extensive. Agricultural production is characterized by a long production period, significant investment in land and other capital, the need for large amounts of agricultural chemicals in the production process, and so on. The rapid growth of agricultural production has also resulted in environmental pollution, unbalanced product structure, overproduction of certain crops, and other issues [9]. Third, there is spatial–temporal heterogeneity in agricultural development. Due to constraints in natural conditions, agricultural production has significant regional and seasonal characteristics, which lead to significant regional imbalances in agricultural development in China. Although agricultural production has greatly developed, traditional development modes are no longer sufficient to meet the needs of economic development at the present stage. Agricultural development also needs to shift from an orientation toward speed to an orientation toward quality. Currently, few studies have investigated high-quality agricultural development. In the context of the new normal of economic development, further research is necessary to promote high-quality agricultural development.
Marketization is an important power that can be used to promote the economy [10,11]. In order to answer the question of how marketization contributed to the high-quality development of Chinese agriculture, we first constructed a system of indicators for the high-quality development of agriculture and constructed an index for the high-quality development of agriculture in China with principal component analysis. Secondly, this paper analyzed the spatial variation in and dynamic evolution of high-quality development of agriculture using the Gini coefficient and kernel density methods. Finally, on the basis of evaluating the high-quality development of Chinese agriculture, we used the QAP method to analyze the impact of marketization reform on the high-quality development of agriculture.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 summarizes the existing research and puts forward the hypotheses, Section 3 outlines the research methodologies and the source of data, Section 4 presents the empirical results, including the spatial and temporal patterns as well as the evolution process and influential factors for high-quality agricultural development in China, Section 5 concludes and provides policy implications, and Section 6 discusses the limitations and future research.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Marketization

Marketization has been seen as a phenomenon that occurs in economic system reforms in transition countries. Many researchers have found that marketization reforms usually have a positive effect on economic growth in the process of marketization reform. The European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD) constructed a system of indicators to measure the effect of marketization reforms on economic growth in its annual transition report, which scores 27 transition countries on various aspects of reform. In an earlier study, Havrylyshyn found a significant explanatory power of marketization reforms on economic growth using the EBRD transition indicators [12]. Demelo used the internal market, external market, and privatization as detailed marketization indicators and found a positive relationship between marketization and economic growth [13].
After reaching a common understanding of the relationship between marketization and economic development, many scholars further studied the pathways through which marketization affects the economy. Marketization can improve the efficiency of resource allocation. This improvement will be necessary for industrialization. Yang proved that marketization could promote industrialization and urbanization, which support the performance of economic development [14]. Mwangi and Kariuki found that marketization could also increase food crop yields, proving that marketization can promote agricultural development [15]. Fan, Aghion, and Iradian proposed that agricultural marketization could promote agricultural technology and thus economic development [16,17,18]. Meanwhile, Fu further discovered that market openness, which is part of marketization, has a negative impact on agricultural technical efficiency in the short term but a positive impact in the long term [19,20,21]. Wan and Van uncovered that the marketization of land markets could reduce the efficiency losses associated with land market fragmentation, increasing the development quality of the economy [22,23].

2.2. High-Quality Development

A growing number of scholars around the world are focusing on development quality rather than only on the production of agriculture. Martinez defined high-quality agricultural development as strong, stable, and sustainable growth; he stated that it is important to promote the quality of agricultural development to improve people’s lives and reduce poverty [24]. Many scholars stressed the importance of the development quality of agriculture. Brown stated that the government should enhance agricultural technology, which could not only boost agricultural productivity but also promote agricultural development quality [25]. King showed that technological innovation in agriculture is an important reason why there is a huge difference in agricultural productivity between developed and develo** countries; he also stated that improving the development quality of agriculture is an important path to reducing the gap in agricultural development [26]. Because agricultural production needs chemical inputs, Shumin highlighted that environmental degradation leads to a deterioration in the quality of agricultural development in China’s reform and opening, hindering its economic and cultural development [27].
The pathway by which marketization affects high-quality agricultural development is characterized by agriculture production. Many scholars further determined the agricultural factors influenced by marketization, with some articles pointing out that the education level of farmers could be influenced by agriculture marketization, which would further affect the yield of crops [28,29]. Zhong identified that land marketization could improve the efficiency of resource allocation by giving more effective play to the land price signal and guiding the combination of production factors to create matches more effectively [30]. Yao also conducted relevant research on the land market; he found that land marketization would also increase the green TFP significantly [31]. Additionally, the marketization of agricultural land could reduce the land price, thus improving the average land productivity by improving land allocation efficiency [32].
In addition to the elements previously mentioned, such as technology, the environment, farmers’ living quality, and the rural government, we speculate that marketization will also affect agriculture through the following several elements. The development of marketization will promote not only the domestic trading of agricultural products but also their exportation to the world; therefore, the external trade of agriculture will also increase. The development of agriculture marketization could promote the development of agriculture on a larger scale, and the demand for agricultural expansion could promote the emergence of the agricultural finance industry and infrastructure development.
The high-quality development of agriculture and marketization has been well-researched, giving us a good basis for our study. Thus, based on the connotations of high-quality development, we further analyzed the promotion of agriculture development by different regional levels of marketization in China. Then, we analyzed the impact of marketization on high-quality agricultural development in detail to find the concrete factors influencing high-quality agricultural development. We also determined the impact of marketization on agricultural development trends.

3. Research Hypotheses

3.1. The Mechanism by Which Marketization Promotes High-Quality Agricultural Development

In China’s economic transition, the market competition mechanism plays an important role in economic development. Market competition means the survival of the fittest. In economic development, the efficiency of resource allocation is an important factor in determining the rate of economic growth and the income gap [33]. Optimizing resource allocation is the basic characteristic of the market economy. The change in resource allocation will induce a change in the production mode. Resources flow into the more efficient sector, which causes industrialization.
Additionally, marketization is the process of price formation with market competition and further adjusts the relationship between supply and demand. Compared with the planned economy, marketization leads to flexible prices under which high-quality products may be sold at a higher price. This flexible price mechanism will encourage producers to focus more resources on the R&D of high-quality products in order to make a profit, thus obtaining advantages in price and competition. The process of market competition may lead to better commodity quality, more patterns, and a more reasonable price. Economic development in various countries has demonstrated the role of marketization in promoting the economy [34] with product innovation.
High-quality agricultural development is a new development mode based on the development of the agricultural industry. High-quality agricultural development cannot be separated from industrialization and high-quality products. In order to promote high-quality agricultural development, optimized resource allocation and flexible prices are needed first. Based on the above relationship, this paper proposes the following:
Hypothesis 1.
The increase in marketization may promote high-quality agricultural development.

3.2. The Mechanism by Which the Degree of Governmental Regulation of the Economy Influences High-Quality Agricultural Development

There have been many classic discussions on government and economic development [35,36,37,38]. Some studies have shown the promotional effect of governmental regulations on economic development [39,40,41,42,43]. However, some studies have proved a negative relationship between them [44,45,46]. Before the reform and opening, the planned economic system was implemented in China. Although it has played a role in promoting economic development, its hindering effect on economic development has also been gradually exposed. After the reform and opening, market-oriented reforms were advocated in China to give full play to the advantages of the market mechanism. Meanwhile, the negative aspects of the markets have been restrained by governmental regulation of the economy.
The market plays an important role in promoting economic development. However, relevant evidence proves that governments also affect economic growth at different stages of the marketization process [47,48,49,50]. At the initial stage of marketization, demand for agricultural products exceeded supply. It was a seller’s market. It was difficult to maintain the balance between supply and demand based solely on the regulatory function of the market, and market failure appeared. At this stage, a good market system and economic functioning system established by governments could regulate the behaviors of market players, which played important roles in resource allocation. Governments avoided the disadvantages of the market mechanism that failed to effectively regulate the supply of public goods with the provision of public goods, particularly agricultural infrastructure. Government policies on agricultural product price protection and agricultural subsidies ensured farmers’ income. After the degree of marketization gradually improves, under the regulation of the market, the concentration of the main production factors in agricultural production, such as technologies, funds, and lands, can promote technical innovation and product development.
Overall, at the initial stage of the marketization process, governments participated extensively in economic operations, which alleviated the misallocation of resources, market failures, and other phenomena caused by the undeveloped market mechanism and effectively boosted economic growth. After the middle stage of the marketization process, the market plays a major role in resource allocation, which promotes the effective circulation of the means of production and improves economic efficiency. The functions of governments and markets are relevant to different economic development situations, and both have great significance for high-quality agricultural development. Therefore, this paper proposes the following:
Hypothesis 2.
In the relationship between the government and the market, the government’s regulatory degree may promote or hinder high-quality agricultural development.

3.3. The Mechanism by Which the Development of the Non-State-Owned Economy Influences High-Quality Agricultural Development

Enterprises of all forms of ownership coexist in transition economies [51,52]. Among them, state-owned enterprises and non-state-owned enterprises are the leading force of national economic development, competing with each other in all industries. In China’s economic reform, the non-state-owned economy has played an important role [53]. It accounts for 75 percent of China’s total output. The rapid development of the non-state-owned economy has prompted the rural population to migrate to cities. The total labor force engaged in agricultural production has declined, which has led to an increase in agricultural productivity. The labor force flowing into the non-state-owned economy lowers the labor price and thus promotes the development of the labor market. The development of the labor market has improved the efficiency of labor factor allocation. Additionally, this further boosts the development of the non-state-owned economy, forming a virtuous cycle. High-quality agricultural development requires continuous improvement in the efficiency of agricultural production. It can be seen from the facts of agricultural development in China, that the development of the non-state-owned economy is closely related to the improvement in agricultural production efficiency. Therefore, this paper proposes the following:
Hypothesis 3.
The development of the non-state-owned economy may boost high-quality agricultural development.

3.4. The Mechanism by Which the Degree of Product Market Development Influences High-Quality Agricultural Development

The development of product markets is the basis for exercising the market’s ability to allocate resources. Additionally, the price regulatory mechanism formed by product marketization is the necessary condition to achieve effective resource allocation. A great deal of classic literature discusses the impact of marketization on economic development [54,55]. In recent years, studies on product marketization have gradually extended to agriculture. The impacts of agricultural product marketization on output, input, technologies, etc., can be found everywhere in the literature [56]. These studies consider the marketization of agricultural products as one of the driving forces for the transformation of subsistence production agriculture into maximization-oriented and market-based production. Such transformation affects not only the yield of agricultural products but also the choice of input factors [57]. There are many theories supporting the promotion of agricultural product marketization [58]. The main reason for this is that the development of agricultural product marketization provides more possibilities for applying new technologies in agricultural production. High-quality agricultural development needs to be driven by innovation. The development of the agricultural product market determines the innovative capabilities of agricultural production. Innovation is related to the promotion of high-quality agriculture development. Therefore, this paper proposes the following:
Hypothesis 4.
The degree of product market development may promote high-quality agricultural development.

3.5. The Mechanism by Which the Degree of Factor Market Development Influences High-Quality Agricultural Development

A well-developed agricultural factor market is a prerequisite for agricultural development [59]. Agriculture is a labor-intensive industry, which means laborers’ skills are the main elements determining production. In an under-developed factor market, it is hard for laborers to improve frequently, and most of them lack the opportunities to improve their skills. In this situation, the productivity of agriculture would not be high because the techniques used remain at a low level. Additionally, it is hard to have technical innovation in agriculture with lower labor skills. In the agricultural goods market, lower productivity represents lower prices; thus, it is hard for the producers to input more capital to improve laborer skills.
Compared with the product market, marketization development of the factor market is relatively slow, and one of the main reasons is the constraint of local governments. Under a planned economy, the local government has the right to order agricultural products with locked prices. However, such interventions distort the factor price and thus distort the resource allocation in factor markets [60]. Much evidence suggests that the distorted factor price makes the production factor price fail to reflect the true factor market supply and demand, and thus causes a mismatch between factor supply and demand in agricultural production [61]. A lower price reduces the motivation for laborers to improve their skills and thus hinders agricultural development.
High-quality agricultural development is green and developmentally friendly to the environment. To solve the pollution problem of current agricultural production, technical improvement is required. Thus, skilled labor is a necessary input for agriculture. To improve labor skills, giving full play to the regulatory role of the factor market to enhance the accuracy of price regulation in the factor market is needed. Therefore, this paper proposes the following:
Hypothesis 5.
The degree of factor market development may positively affect high-quality agricultural development.

3.6. The Mechanism by Which the Level of Market Order Influences High-Quality Agricultural Development

It is necessary to give full play to the price regulation role of the agricultural product market for high-quality agricultural development, and price regulation depends on the continuous improvement in market order. A good market order can prevent monopolies and vicious competition to protect the interests of both consumers and producers, thus promoting the effective operation of the price mechanism and the reasonable distribution of production elements as well as the level of market order, which further increases production efficiency [62,63]. High-quality agricultural development is a kind of sustainable development that needs a stable and healthy development environment. Additionally, based on the important role of the level of market order in the developmental environment, this paper proposes the following:
Hypothesis 6.
The level of market order may promote high-quality agricultural development.

4. Research Methods and Data Source

This paper sets up an evaluation index system for high-quality agricultural development based on the connotation of high-quality development and obtains indexes for high-quality agricultural development from 2009 to 2019 by measuring using principal component analysis. Then, this paper measures and decomposes regional differences in China’s high-quality agricultural development using the Dagum Gini coefficient, describes the dynamic evolution process of the differences using kernel density estimation, and analyzes their influencing factors using the Quadratic Assignment Procedure (QAP) method. All the methods and data used and involved will be explained in this section.

4.1. Measurement Indicators

Understanding the connotation of high-quality development accurately is the basis for setting up a scientific and reasonable measurement system for high-quality development. This paper ascertains that high-quality development is an inevitable requirement for economic development to a certain extent, is a development mode beyond the economic category, and is a mode emphasizing quality. Therefore, the measurement system for high-quality development should not only include costs and benefits according to economics but also should take the internal impetus, regional coordination, sustainability, inclusiveness, regional differences, and other aspects of development into consideration. High-quality development is based on growth, and high-quality agricultural development also needs to ensure the stable growth of agriculture. From the perspective of new development philosophy, this paper sets up a measurement system for high-quality agricultural development (see Table 1 for the indication system in detail) in five dimensions, including innovation, coordination, greenness, opening, and sharing. After selecting the indexes, we determine the weight of each index using principal component analysis.
In this paper, all inverse indexes are positively processed using reciprocal forms, and the basic indexes are standardized using the equalization method. This paper first obtains the basic index data on the high-quality agricultural development of 30 provinces (the Tibet Autonomous Region is not included as it has a significant amount of missing data) in China from 2009 to 2019 and then uses the factor analysis process in the statistical software SPSS to perform a global principal component analysis on the indicator data for the high-quality agricultural development index. The results of both the KMO Test and Bartlett’s Test of Sphericity reached critical values, indicating that the variables are suitable for principal component analysis. When performing global principal component analysis, the covariance matrix is applied, and six principal components are extracted according to the principle of the variance cumulative contribution rate Qm ≥ 85%. Using the proportion of the eigenvalues for each principal component to the total eigenvalue as the weight, weighing and summarizing the scores of the 6 principal components for all the provinces over the years, this paper finally works out the high-quality agricultural development index of the 30 provinces in China.

4.2. Source of Data and Explanation

The basic data used in this paper come from the China Statistical Yearbook, China rural statistical yearbook, and China Agricultural Statistical Yearbook published by China Statistics Press from 2009 to 2019. The data on agricultural carbon emissions come from the China Emission Accounts and Datasets (CEADs).
The marketization index data refer to the methods used to set up Chinese marketization indexes mentioned in the article by Wang ** effect among different regions. This paper divides the 30 provinces (except Tibet) in China’s mainland into 3 regions: the east, the center, and the west (note: they are divided according to the economic development status. The eastern region includes Bei**g, Tian**, Hebei, Liaoning, Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Fujian, Shandong, Guangdong, and Hainan. The central region includes Shanxi, Jilin, Heilongjiang, Anhui, Jiangxi, Henan, Hubei, and Hunan. The western region includes Guangxi, Inner Mongolia, Chongqing, Sichuan, Guizhou, Yunnan, Shaanxi, Gansu, Qinghai, Ningxia, and **njiang).
First, we calculate the overall Gini coefficient G, the intra-regional Gini coefficient Gj, and the inter-regional Gini coefficient Gjh using the respective calculation equations as follows:
G = j = 1 k h = 1 k i = 1 n j r = 1 n h | Y j i Y h r | 2 n 2 Y ¯
G j j = 1 2 Y ¯ j i = 1 n j r = 1 n j | Y j i Y j r | n 2
G j h = i = 1 n j r = 1 n k | Y j i Y h r | n j n h ( Y ¯ j + Y ¯ h )
In these equations, k = 3 represents the number of regions, n = 30 represents the number of provinces, Y represents the average value of the high-quality agricultural development indexes for all provinces, Yj(Yh) represents the average value of the high-quality agricultural development indexes for the region j(h), and Yji(Yhr) represents the level of high-quality agricultural development in the province i(r) in the region j(h).
Second, we define the relevant variables. P j = n j / n , S j = n j Y ¯ j / n Y ¯ , and D j h = M j h N j h M j h + N j h represent the relative influences of the high-quality agricultural development indexes between two regions; M j h = 0 d F j ( Y ) 0 Y ( Y x ) d F h ( x ) represents the difference in the high-quality agricultural development indexes between the regions, and when Y ¯ j > Y ¯ h , Mjh represents the weighted average of all the difference values for the high-quality agricultural development indexes Y j i Y h r under the condition Y j i Y h r > 0 . N j h = 0 d F h ( Y ) 0 Y ( Y x ) d F j ( x ) is the hypervariable first moment, and when Y ¯ j > Y ¯ h , Njh represents the weighted average of all Y h r Y j i under the condition Y h r Y j i > 0 .
Finally, we calculate the contribution of the intra-regional differences Gw, the contribution of inter-regional differences Gnb, and the hypervariable density contribution Gt using the respective calculation equations as follows:
G w = j = 1 k G j j P j S j
G n b = j = 2 k h = 1 j 1 G j h D j h ( P j S h + P h S j )
G t = j = 2 k h = 1 j 1 G j h ( P j S h + P h S j ) ( 1 D j h )
In this paper, we calculate the Gini coefficient for the spatial distribution of high-quality agricultural development in 30 provinces in China from 2009 to 2019 and perform regional decomposition to research the inter-regional differences in high-quality agricultural development.

4.3.3. Kernel Density Analysis

Kernel density estimation is an important non-parametric estimation method that focuses on the data and researches their distribution characteristics [70]. It has become a mainstream method to research unbalanced distribution. This paper uses this method to describe the overall shape and distribution characteristics of high-quality agricultural development. As this method requires no prior information on models and can describe the distribution shape of variables by estimating the continuous density curve of random variables, kernel density estimation curves at different periods can represent the high-quality development statuses at different periods. Using images, this method directly displays the sizes and the changing processes in the regional differences in high-quality development [71]. Assume the density function for the random variable X is f(x), the probability density of point x can be estimated with Equation (7). In the equation, N is the number of observation values, h is the bandwidth, K(·) is the kernel function, which is a weighting function or a smooth transition function, Xi is the independent and identically distributed observation value, and x is the average value.
f ( x ) = 1 N h i = 1 N K ( X i x h )
K ( x ) = 1 2 π exp ( x 2 2 )
According to the different expression forms of the kernel density functions, the kernel functions can be divided into Gaussian kernel, Epanechnikov kernel, triangular kernel, quartic kernel, etc. This paper selects the commonly used Gaussian kernel function for estimation. The expression of the Gaussian kernel function is shown in Equation (8): as there is no definite function expression for non-parametric estimations, we need to examine the distribution changes using graphic comparison. We can obtain the position, shape, and extensibility of the variable distribution using the graphs for the kernel density estimation results.
This paper uses kernel density estimation to analyze the dynamic evolution of the high-quality agricultural development distribution in China within the sample investigation period. It not only describes the overall shape of the high-quality agricultural development but also grasps the dynamic characteristics of the distribution of the regional high-quality agricultural development distribution using a comparison among different periods.

4.3.4. QAP Method

When exploring the influencing factors for regional differences, we regard the difference between regions as a relationship. Additionally, using relational data can better explore the interaction between two individuals [72]. The econometric model for the relational data set in this paper is as follows:
Y = β 0 + β 1 X + β 2 Z + U
where β0, β1, and β2 are the parameters to be estimated; X and Y are the explanatory and explained variables; Z is the control variable; and U is the residual term. In the relational data model, all variables are square matrices of order n, where the observations yij, xij, and zij in the matrix, respectively, represent the difference between the explained variables, explanatory variables, and control variables in two regions, and their values can be obtained by calculating yiyj, xixj, and zizj. Since the observations are the differences in indicators between two regions, the main diagonal elements are all 0 when i = j. For the relational data model, the correlation coefficient between the column and row elements in the residual matrix U is not zero; that is, the column and row elements are not independent but correlated, which leads to an autocorrelation issue in the econometric model [73]. In addition to the autocorrelation problem, there is also serious multicollinearity among variables in the form of relational data. If the traditional statistical test method is used, the variance in and standard deviation of the parameter estimates will increase, and the significance test for the variables will be meaningless [74,75]. In order to solve the problem of autocorrelation and multicollinearity in relational data models, QAP, a non-parametric test method based on random permutation, becomes essential [76]. This method converts the relationship matrix into a long vector, calculates the regression coefficients, and then performs random replacements to judge the significance of the parameter estimates. Its implementation consists of the following two steps. The first step is long vector regression. The variable matrix in Equation (9) is transformed into an n × (n − 1)-dimensional column vector, that is, a long vector, and then OLS estimation is performed on the long vector to obtain the regression coefficient set Γ(Y, XZ) and goodness of fit R2. As mentioned above, due to the autocorrelation problem of relational data, the standard error obtained using the OLS estimation method is wrong [77], and the significance of traditional statistical test methods (such as t-test and F-test) will no longer be reliable. The second step is random permutation and a statistical test. A linear relationship between X and Z is assumed in Equation (9), as shown in Equation (10), and E is the classical residual term. If δ ≠ 0, then there is multicollinearity between X and Z, and the estimator can be expressed using Equation (11), where δ ^ is the OLS estimator from Equation (10).
X = δ Z + E
ε ^ X Z = X δ ^ Z
Residual matrix permutation requires random permutation of both a row and a column in ε ^ X Z to obtain a new residual matrix π ( ε ^ X Z ) . After several random permutations, Equation (12) can be used to estimate the reference value of the test statistic.
Y = β 0 + β 1 π ( ε ^ X Z ) + β 2 Z + U
At this point, Equation (12) is identical to Equation (9) under the null hypothesis β1 = 0. If the estimation error δ ^ δ can be ignored, then the residual matrix after random permutation has the same distribution as E, which means the following:
π ( ε ^ X Z ) = π [ ( δ δ ^ ) Z + E ) ]
We can repeat this step many times and save the regression coefficients and goodness of fit R2 after each random permutation to obtain the regression coefficient set Γ ( Y , π ( ε ^ X Z ) ) ; then, we can estimate the standard error of the statistic. Assuming that after mtotal random permutations, the number of times that the regression coefficient generated with the permutation is greater than or equal to or less than or equal to the long vector regression coefficient in the first step is expressed using mlarge and msmall, respectively. Then, we can obtain two proportions: one is the proportion of regression coefficients generated with random permutations that are greater than or equal to the regression coefficients of the long vector in the first step, denoted using plarge, where plarge = mlarge/mtotal; the other one is the proportion of regression coefficients generated with random permutations that are less than or equal to the regression coefficients of the long vector in the first step, denoted using psmall, where psmall = msmall/mtotal. Since the conditions of plarge and psmall overlap, their sum need not equal one. In the statistical test, the above two proportions can be directly regarded as the minimum significance level for rejecting the null hypothesis—that is, the statistical p-value [L]. The two-tailed test is used for the regression coefficient. Therefore, if the regression coefficient is positive, plarge is used as the p-value for the statistical test. Conversely, if the regression coefficient is negative, psmall is used as the p-value for the statistical test. In addition to being able to compute the p-values of the regression coefficients, random permutation can also compute the p-values of R2. Unlike the two-tailed test for the regression coefficients, R2 uses a one-tailed test, so the p-value of R2 is expressed as the ratio of the number of times that random permutation produces R2 greater than or equal to the long vector regression R2 in the first step to the total number of random permutations.
In this paper, the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development are jointly determined using the marketization level, industrial structural level, labor market characteristics, and other factors. This paper uses the differences in economic indexes, such as the index for high-quality agricultural development and the index for marketization degree, between different regions as the data set, the difference matrices formed with various sub-systems as the explanatory variables, and the difference matrices of the high-quality agricultural development indexes as the explained variables. Considering that QAP does not need to assume independence of explanatory variables, which can effectively avoid multicollinearity, this paper applies the QAP regression method to perform a regression analysis on the influential factors for the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development.
This paper applies the annual data from 30 provinces (excluding Tibet) in China’s mainland in 2009–2019 and uses the differences in the high-quality agricultural development in the provinces as the explained variables, the inter-regional differences in marketization indexes as the explanatory variables, and the differences in the industrial structure, the urbanization rate, the old age dependency ratio, and the geographical distance as the control variables. The explained variables, the explanatory variables, and the control variables are set as follows:
The regional differences in high-quality agricultural development. This paper uses the above-mentioned high-quality agricultural development indexes for the provinces to construct the matrix of the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development.
The regional differences in marketization. Applying the marketization indexes for the provinces as the proxy variables of marketization to construct the matrices of regional differences in marketization, this paper also further investigates the impacts of the five sub-indicators of marketization degree, including the degree of governmental regulation of the economy, the development of the non-state-owned economy, the development of the product market, the development of the factor market, and the level of market order. This helps us to investigate the mechanism by which the marketization degree influences the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development from the micro-perspective.
Regional differences in industrial structure. As the industrial development level in each region differs, the development of the industrial structure in each region is not synchronous. The industrial structural level impacts high-quality development. In order to avoid measurement error in high-quality agricultural development caused by the differences in industrial structure, this paper uses the proportion of the added value from the tertiary industry to the added value from the secondary industry as the proxy variable for the industrial structure to construct the matrix of the regional difference in the industrial structure.
Regional differences in the urbanization rate. The level of urbanization varies from region to region, with different numbers of people engaged in agricultural production and different regions. In order to avoid measurement error in high-quality agricultural development caused by the differences in agricultural scale in the regions, this paper uses the urbanization rate (the proportion of the urban population to the total population) as the proxy variable for urbanization and constructs the matrix of regional difference in urbanization based on the urbanization rate measurement.
Regional differences in the old age dependency ratio. The population’s age level impacts the regional economic vitality and the agricultural labor supply level. In order to avoid measurement error in high-quality agricultural development caused by differences in age, this paper uses the regional differences in the old age dependency ratio as one of the control variables and uses the proportion of the elderly population to the gross population as the proxy variable for the old age dependency ratio, and thus constructs the matrices of regional difference in the old age dependency ratio for the provinces.
Geographical distance. Due to the spillover and spread effects of technology and innovation, the regions geographically close to each other always share similar technology and innovation levels. In order to avoid errors in high-quality measurement in adjacent regions caused by technology spillover, this paper uses geographical distance as one of the control variables. The interprovincial geographical distance is calculated and obtained using ArcGis.

5. Research Results

5.1. Indexes for High-Quality Agricultural Development in China

According to the constructed high-quality development indexes, this paper applies principal component analysis to measure the levels of high-quality agricultural development in 30 provinces in China. (This paper first obtains the basic data from 30 provinces in China from 2009 to 2019 and then uses the factor analysis process in SPSS to perform a global principal component analysis on the indicator data for the high-quality agricultural development index. Using the proportion of the eigenvalues for each principal component to the total eigenvalue as the weight, this paper finally works out the high-quality agricultural development index for the 30 provinces in China. Please see the Section 4.1 for detail process.).
Due to space limitations, the principal component analysis results and the high-quality development indexes for each province in each year are displayed in detail in Appendix A and will only be further processed and illustrated in the main body of this paper. Figure 1 shows the temporal trend and the provincial differences in the indexes for high-quality agricultural development in China. In Figure 1a, the values on the ordinate are the average values of the high-quality agricultural development for each province in that year. China’s high-quality agricultural development index shows a year-by-year upward trend, increasing from below −0.3 in 2009 to about 0.3 in 2019. Except for the curve in 2013 and 2015 being relatively flat, all the other years show continuous high-speed growth. In Figure 1b, the values on the ordinate are the average values of the high-quality agricultural development for that province over the years. There are uneven regional developments in high-quality agricultural development. Additionally, it shows a distribution rule of high in the east and low in the west. Among the eastern provinces, Bei**g, Tian**, and Zhejiang have the highest high-quality agricultural development indexes, all higher than 0.4. Most of the values for the central provinces are around 0. Additionally, among the western provinces, the high-quality agricultural development levels for Guizhou, Yunnan, and Gansu are lower than those for the other provinces, all below −0.4. There are large differences in agricultural development among the provinces. It is necessary to further investigate the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development and its influential factors.

5.2. The Regional Differences in High-Quality Agricultural Development in China

In this section, we calculate the Gini coefficient for the spatial distribution of high-quality agricultural development in 30 provinces in China from 2009 to 2019. The results are shown in Table 2. The Gini coefficients for the high-quality agricultural development in the provinces show a year-by-year downward trend, drop** from 0.286 in 2009 to 0.148 in 2019, indicating that the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development are continuously narrowing. In other words, the agricultural development level for each province converges with time and gradually tends to balance.
Looking at the columns with the intra-regional Gini coefficient in the table, we can see that the intra-regional coefficients for the central region are between 0.030 and 0.068 in past years, the smallest among the three regions, which shows the central region is develo** in a more balanced way. Meanwhile, values for the western provinces lie between 0.130 and 0.302, which shows that the western region is develo** in an unbalanced way. Additionally, the eastern region follows. However, such an imbalance is decreasing year by year; the intra-regional Gini coefficient for the western provinces has dropped from 0.302 in 2009 to 0.130 in 2019, less than half of the value in the past.
The inter-regional Gini coefficient shows the differences in the high-quality agricultural development in different regions and provinces. According to the coefficients in 2009, the difference between the eastern and western regions is 0.480, the difference between the central and western regions is 0.307, and the difference between the eastern and central regions is 0.228. This shows that the difference between the eastern and western regions is the largest, but such difference is decreasing year by year, drop** from 0.480 in 2009 to 0.248 in 2019. This distribution is consistent with the information provided in Figure 1.
According to the contribution rates in the table, regional differences in the high-quality agricultural development in China mainly come from inter-regional differences. The fluctuation range lies within 77.10–80.512% and is roughly stabilized at about 78%. Additionally, the contribution rates from the intra-regional differences fluctuate between 18.383% and 20.316%, less than 20% most of the time. The difference distributions in different years are stable, indicating that the intra-regional difference and the inter-regional difference are improved simultaneously as the total Gini coefficient decreases.

5.3. The Dynamic Evolution of High-Quality Agricultural Development in China

This paper uses the Gaussian kernel function to draw a 2D diagram showing the kernel density estimation for the high-quality agricultural development indexes of 30 provinces in China (see Figure 2). We can see in Figure 2a that the differences in the high-quality agricultural development of 30 provinces in China vary slightly within the sample investigation period. Additionally, compared with 2009, the density function center in 2019 moved to the left, which indicates that the level of high-quality agricultural development improved overall, coinciding with the aforementioned temporal trend in high-quality development. The peak value and the size of the change range are basically unchanged, which indicates that the annual change in the regional difference level is relatively stable. The differences among the provinces in the east, west, and center still exist.
Figure 2b–d describes the distribution evolution of the high-quality agricultural development levels for the eastern, western, and central regions, respectively, during the investigation period. For the eastern region, the density function center becomes narrower year by year while moving to the right. Additionally, compared with 2009, the peak value in 2019 is significantly enlarged, and the variation range becomes smaller, indicating that the regional difference in the eastern provinces is significantly narrowed in 2019. Additionally, for the central region, the peak value drops, and the variation range remains unchanged as the density function center moves to the right, indicating that the degree of polarization in the central provinces becomes smaller. For the western provinces, the shape becomes wider as the density function center moves to the right. Compared with 2009, the peak value in 2019 significantly dropped, and the wave crest flattened. The quantity of the wave crest changed from a single crest into two insignificant crests, indicating that the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development were enlarged in 2019. Overall, the regional difference in high-quality agricultural development shows a narrowing trend in the eastern and central regions, while the western region shows an enlarging trend. This is mainly because the agricultural development levels in the eastern and central regions are higher, and the development is relatively balanced. However, due to the great differences in the geographic environment and the economic development level, the imbalance in agricultural development is higher for the provinces in the western region.

5.4. Impact of Marketization on the Inter-Regional Differences in High-Quality Agricultural Development

Table 3 reports the QAP regression results for the entire sample period. The QAP regression results identified two categories of regression coefficients: the non-standardized regression coefficients and standardized regression coefficients, respectively. According to Borgatti et al. [78], a standardized regression coefficient is a regression coefficient obtained using estimation after all matrices are standardized. Additionally, the non-standardized regression coefficient is the regression coefficient obtained after estimating the original matrices. Compared to non-standardized regression coefficients, standardized regression coefficients have two significant advantages. One is that the standardized regression coefficients are unaffected by observation dimensions, while non-standardized regression coefficients are closely related to observation dimensions. The other is that standardized regression coefficients can provide more useful information. Though standardized regression coefficients and non-standardized regression coefficients are different in value, they share the same symbol, which means that standardization does not change the direction of variable action. Considering the regression result from the same model, being constrained by observation dimensions, it is meaningless to compare the non-standardized regression coefficients of different variables. As standardization has eliminated the impact of observation dimensions, the standardized regression coefficients of different variables can be compared directly. Furthermore, the focus of the analysis exactly lies in comparing the sizes of standardized regression coefficients. This will help us analyze the differences in the influential strength of different variables on the explained variables.
According to the regression results from Model I in Table 3, the non-standardized regression coefficient for the marketization index is 0.094, while the standardized regression coefficient increased to 0.464, both passing the 1% significance test. This result shows that the marketization degree significantly impacts the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development. Within the sample period, without considering the control variables, the marketization degree played an important role in the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development in China.
Model II in Table 3 presents the results after considering the control variables. After adjustment, R2 increased from 0.215 in Model I to 0.440, which means that the five matrix variables, including the marketization degree, have higher interpretability for the variation in the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development. However, the standardized coefficient for the marketization index decreased from 0.464 in Model I to 0.225 in Model II. This is because the other variables in Model II, such as the industrial structure, the urbanization rate, and other factors, are related to the marketization degree. Except for the old age dependency ratio, all the other variables have positive standardized regression coefficients. Comparing the standardized regression coefficients in Model II, the influence intensities of these factors on the differences in high-quality agricultural development in China can be ordered from high to low according to the urbanization rate (0.431), the marketization index (0.225), the geographic distance (0.135), the industrial structure (0.112), and the old age dependency ratio (−0.087). However, among these variables, only the marketization index, the urbanization rate, and the geographic distance passed the significance test. As previously mentioned, the degree of marketization positively impacts the high-quality development of regional agriculture, with urbanization playing a crucial role in this process. This is due to urbanization absorbing excess rural labor force and allowing for more efficient allocation of labor resources and other factors, optimizing employment choices for rural populations, and enabling large-scale and specialized agricultural development. Geographical distance exhibits a positive correlation with inter-provincial agricultural development differences. This is because neighboring provinces often share similar climates, cultures, and policy systems, resulting in greater similarity in their agricultural models and lower transaction costs. While geographical distance cannot be objectively reduced, the government can reduce commodity circulation costs by lowering transportation expenses and facilitating mutual learning regarding policies and institutions. The impact of industrial structure is not statistically significant, as it exerts a multifaceted influence on agricultural development. On the one hand, industrial upgrading can absorb the rural labor force, streamline and enhance agricultural development, and provide technical and market support for its advancement, which shows that industrial structure positively affects agricultural development. On the other hand, when facing the national demand market, the agricultural development of a province may produce a scale effect and occupy a proportion of higher industries in the output value for the province. When the agricultural development of a province has comparative advantages, the industrial allocation selection of the province often serves the optimization of national industrial allocation, which shows that the province’s industrial structure is negatively correlated with the level of agricultural development. Therefore, the influence of the industrial structure on agriculture depends on the industrial objective and national orientation of the province. The coefficient for the old age dependency ratio is not significant, suggesting that aging is currently only a potential problem. In other words, in terms of the degree of marketization and significant influencing factors, reducing the imbalance between these factors can effectively narrow the gap between regional agricultural high-quality development. This provides more powerful empirical evidence for the theoretical logic of this paper.

5.5. Impact of Marketization Indicators on the Inter-Regional Differences in High-Quality Agricultural Development

QAP regression is used in this section to analyze the impacts of marketization sub-indicators on high-quality agricultural development (see Table 4). In Model I, the influence intensities of the sub-indicators on the differences in high-quality agricultural development in China can be ordered from high to low as the factor market development (0.544), the level of market order (0.476), the non-state-owned economic development (0.243), the degree of governmental regulation of the economy (0.212), and the product market development (−0.113). All other variables passed the significance test except for the indicator for product market development.
In Model II, after adding control variables, the Adj.R2 of all regressions increased significantly. The standardized coefficients for marketization sub-indicators also decreased to different degrees. The impact of non-state-owned economic development is the largest, 0.213, and next is the impact of the market’s level of order, 0.201, and the impact of the factor market development, 0.177. The impact of product market development is 0.053, which is still not significant, and the impact of the degree of governmental regulation of the economy dropped to 0.068 and became insignificant. It can be seen from this that the impact of the marketization degree on high-quality agricultural development mainly focuses on three aspects: non-state-owned economic development, factor market development, and the market’s level of order. The imbalance in these factors among the regions is more likely to lead to regional differences in high-quality agricultural development. Non-state-owned economic development is the most important factor in promoting high-quality agricultural development. Because of the promotion of non-state-owned economic development, the labor needed for agriculture decreased, promoting agricultural productivity. Additionally, the increased market level and factor market degree can improve the agricultural trading environment. The lower influence degree of the product market may be caused by the fact that the developed logistics industry expanded the market of agricultural products to the entire country.

5.6. Temporal Characteristics of the Impacts of Marketization Indexes on the Inter-Regional Differences in High-Quality Agricultural Development

In this part, we divide the samples into two groups to perform QAP regression, respectively, to investigate the temporal characteristics of the impacts of marketization indexes on the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development (see Table 5). Without control variables, the coefficient for the marketization index is 0.396 in the earlier period and rises to 0.491 in the later period, and it passes the significance test in both the earlier and the later periods. For every sub-indicator for the marketization degree, the coefficient rises in different degrees in the later period compared to that in the earlier period. In the group regression, the market level of order and the development degree of the factor market are still the two factors with the greatest impacts, whose coefficients rise, respectively, from 0.402 and 0.433 to 0.516 and 0.522, while the coefficient for the degree of governmental regulation of the economy rises from 0.163 to 0.205, the coefficient of the non-state-owned economic development rises from 0.164 to 0.327, and the coefficient of the development degree of the product market rises from 0.064 to 0.177. The influence coefficient values of the three factors increased, and so did their degrees of significance.
After the control variables are added in, the total index coefficients for marketization decreased in both periods. However, compared with the value of 0.111 in the earlier period, the influence of the total marketization index rises to 0.316 in the later period, and the influence increases significantly. This indicates that the significance of marketization to high-quality agricultural development is continuously enhanced. In terms of the sub-indicators, the impacts of the degree of governmental regulation of the economy and the product market development are not significant in either period. This indicates that the marketization reform in China gradually deepens, and the degree of governmental regulation of the economy becomes weaker. The impact of non-state-owned economic development increases from 0.131 in the earlier period to 0.301 in the later period, and the impacts of factor market development and the market level of order are only significant in the later periods, with values of 0.267 and 0.295, respectively. This indicates that the non-state-owned economy is increasingly important for high-quality development after the marketization degree improves. Overall, the impact of all sub-indicators for marketization on high-quality agricultural development becomes greater in the later period, while some indexes are only significant in the later period. This proves that the development of marketization has a significant promotional effect on high-quality agricultural development.
Next, this paper carries out year-by-year QAP regression and dynamically reveals the impacts of the marketization degree on the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development. Additionally, based on the QAP regression, it draws the standardized regress indexes in Figure 3 (not considering control variables) and Figure 4 (considering control variables).
According to Figure 3, without controlling for the other variables, the factor market development and the market level of order have higher impacts than the other sub-indicators. This result is consistent with the finding from the regression on the indexes. In terms of the variation tendency in influence strength, the influence of the non-state-owned economic development increased, while the impacts of other sub-indicators were stable in 2009–2014 and started to show an upward trend after 2014. After controlling for the other variables (see Figure 4), the impacts of all sub-indicators decreased, but the differences between sub-indicators also narrowed. Except for some certain years, among the five sub-indicators for the marketization degree, the strength of influence for the product market development and the degree of governmental regulation of the economy was comparatively low, but non-state-owned economic development and the market’s level of order always had stronger impacts than the other indexes on the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development in China, and the time trends in the latter two were similar to those in Figure 3. The influence of the factor market development shows larger volatility. Therefore, according to the year-by-year QAP regression results, it is consistent with the conclusion from the index and period investigations. The development of the non-state-owned economy, the development degree of the factor market, and the market level of order are the three factors with the greatest impact on the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development, and such impacts gradually intensify over time.

6. Discussion

This paper calculated the high-quality agricultural development indexes for 30 provinces in China and indicated the level of high-quality agricultural development using an average value. The average value of the index raised from −0.3 in 2009 to about 0.3 in 2019. China’s level of high-quality agricultural development shows a continuous and rapid upward trend. Meanwhile, the level of high-quality agricultural development in China keeps rising, and there is a difference between the levels in the east and the west, showing the characteristics of being higher in the east and lower in the west. The gap between the high-quality development in provinces in the eastern and central regions shows a narrowing trend, while the provinces in the west show an expanding trend. Such a difference is caused by the different geographic environments and economic development levels in the provinces in the eastern and western regions. We found that the differences in high-quality agricultural development mainly come from the regional differences when decomposing the differences in high-quality agricultural development with the Gini coefficient [79,80]. This result is consistent with the regional economies of China. There are differences between the west, east, and central areas. Economic development is more unbalanced in the west, and there are large areas of land unsuitable for agriculture and human life [81,82]. These differences in economic development caused disparities in high-quality agricultural development.
We applied kernel density estimation to describe the progress of high-quality development in different regions. This paper found that the annual changes in regional differences in these 30 provinces and regions in China are stable, and the largest difference lies between the eastern and western regions. This also supports the conclusion about regional economic development [83]. Furthermore, the analysis of the internal differences among the regions indicates that the gap between the high-quality agricultural development in provinces in the eastern and central regions shows a narrowing trend, while the western region demonstrates an expanding trend. This is because the agricultural development levels in the eastern and central regions are higher and more balanced [84,85,86].
Because of the importance of agricultural development, we looked for a path to improve the quality of agriculture. Using QAP regression, we found that the marketization degree significantly impacts the differences in high-quality agricultural development in the new normal stage. The importance of this impact strengthens gradually over time. This is because the degree of marketization continuously improves [87].
These results provide another proper way to promote high-quality agricultural development. Some papers suggest encouraging agricultural technical innovation to realize high-quality development [88,89,90,91]. Based on these results, we further conclude that marketization is a method that can be used to encourage technical innovation, which is necessary for high-quality development. In addition to innovation, some scholars suggest improving farmers’ skills and reducing the use of chemicals to realize sustainable development [92,93,94,95,96,97]. Given this paper’s results, we can conclude that factor marketization could be a useful way to settle prices and improve the skills of laborers in agriculture production.
Moreover, given the results for the sub-indicators, we could also increase the development of the non-state-owned economy to promote high-quality agricultural development. As many previous research papers have mentioned, the non-state-owned economy accounts for nearly 70% of employment in China, which could solve the labor surplus during the process of high-quality development [98,99]. When labor skills have been improved, most low-skilled labor needs to be transferred from the high-quality agriculture industry to other industries without requirements for technology. These industries are mainly found in the non-state-owned economy. Throughout China’s rapid economic growth, the non-state-owned economy played a key role in the transition. Additionally, it will continue to be a vital element in high-quality development.
There are two other elements that are important to high-quality development: the factor market and market order. Previous research has pointed out that marketization is one of the crucial steps needed for determining a price [100]. In other words, marketization helps to reasonably adjust prices according to supply and demand. High-quality development requires efficient resource allocation, which is needed to promote marketization. Because agriculture is a labor-intense industry, the coefficient for the factor market is sufficient. Additionally, this result indicates that the factor market is important in labor-intensive industries [101]. With the development of marketization, market order is also necessary to guarantee efficient resource allocation. In previous papers examining sustainable development, most research aimed to find the affecting elements in the market itself, but they failed to consider this problem along with the development of marketization. In this paper, we extend our research to the field of market development. We think, in the process of market development, market order will play a more important role than before. We can conclude that agricultural development can still be promoted with marketization.
Given the differences in different regions, in order to narrow the regional differences in high-quality development, it is necessary to boost high-quality agricultural development in the west. It is further necessary to provide more preferential policies and production factors to the west to narrow the regional differences in high-quality agricultural development in the east and west.
In addition to the sub-indicators for the marketization degree, urbanization and geographic distance also affect and result in differences in the high-quality development of regional agriculture. These two elements are different from the other research. Urbanization can be regarded as one of the results of marketization. It might be interesting to look further into the relationship between marketization and development. Moreover, geographic distance affects the cost of integrating markets. We will consider this situation and try to determine the function of the market’s formation in high-quality development.

7. Conclusions

The degree of marketization has a significant impact on high-quality agricultural development, which is introduced with the development of the non-state-owned economy, the development of the factor market, and the changes in market order. Marketization should be considered an important channel for development and be vigorously promoted.
First, it is important to vigorously promote the development of non-state-owned enterprises in rural areas. Based on previous research, the non-state-owned economy played an important role in the development of China. It provides more jobs and promotes innovation. We found similar results to those previous findings. The non-state-owned economy improves innovation in rural areas and attracts intelligent workers. Therefore, it is reasonable to further energize the development and transformation of non-state-owned enterprises in rural areas using preferential policies and capital support. Driving the development of the rural labor market with non-state-owned enterprises is an important force for high-quality development in rural areas. To reach this point, it is necessary to create proper conditions for the flow of agricultural production factors so as to realize the optimization of the agricultural production structure and the enhancement of agricultural productivity.
Second, it is important to promote the development of the factor market, rationalize the structure, and reduce the degree of government intervention in the factor market. Given the characteristics of agriculture production, this factor is one the most important elements in agricultural production, especially human resources and capital. Agriculture is a typical labor-intensive industry. The reasonable return on labor is one of the key points in high-quality agricultural development. It is important for the price mechanism to play a full role in adjusting and controlling the agricultural production factors to alleviate the distorted pricing of agricultural production factors. Next, the rational flow of production factors is crucial to deploy the resources of the factor market more accurately. This can help to solve the mismatch between supply and demand of production factors in agricultural production and promote high-quality agricultural development.
The third suggestion is to strengthen market supervision and standardize rectification. With the development of marketization in China, many researchers have found that market supervision is an important part that needs to be promoted. China has transferred from a planned economy to a market economy, and these two different mechanisms require different levels of supervision. When the market plays a decisive role in resource allocation, rectification will be an important step in transformation. It is also important to counter monopolies and unfair competition rules, as well as optimize the market competition ecology. Strengthening the design of the marketization regulatory system and enhancing the efforts and efficiency of law enforcement to create a market environment of fair competition are also crucial. It is paramount to provide a good market order for the agricultural product market to improve the efficiency of product exchange and information transfer, to realize the reasonable docking of the demands with the suppliers of agricultural production, and to solve the unreasonable allocation of production factors caused by the mismatch between supply and demand for agricultural products.
The research in this paper enriches the study of high-quality agricultural development and marketization. Due to the constraints of data availability, there are still some issues requiring further discussion. The development of economic society shows different characteristics at different stages and affects the environment of high-quality agricultural development. Due to data limitations, this paper fails to fully consider the characteristics of economic and social development in different regions and struggles to measure the level of high-quality agricultural development in different regions accurately.
In this work, the global principal component analysis method is used to construct the agricultural high-quality development index, which can eliminate the influence of collinearity among sub-indicators, extract main features from the raw data, and reduce the influence of redundant information. However, in dimension reduction, there may also be a loss of effective information on sub-indicators, resulting in inaccurate results. In addition, the QAP method is used to study the influence of inter-provincial marketization differences on the difference in the agricultural high-quality development level. Some control variables are selected, and their coefficients and significance are explained. However, this explanation is preliminary, and how these variables affect the differences in agricultural development, as well as their relationship with the degree of marketization, needs further investigation and research.
In recent years, the digital economy, as a new production factor, has greatly boosted economic development. The digital economy has also influenced agricultural production directly and indirectly. Subsequent research needs to consider the influential mechanisms of digitalized production factors on high-quality agricultural development. Under the condition of increasingly pressing environmental constraints, the green constraints of high-quality agricultural development are also gradually becoming stronger. It is necessary to further consider the constraint mechanism for environmental factors and adjust the measurement indexes for high-quality development.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Y.Q. and M.G.; methodology, H.W.; software, H.W.; validation, J.L. and S.S.; formal analysis, Y.Q. and H.D.; investigation, M.G.; resources, H.W.; data curation, H.W.; writing—original draft preparation, H.W.; writing—review and editing, J.L.; visualization, J.L.; supervision, Y.Q. and H.D.; project administration, Y.Q. and J.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data presented in this study are available upon request from the corresponding author.

Acknowledgments

This work was supported by the Faculty of Economics and the Centre of Excellence in Econometrics at Chiang Mai University.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Global principal component analysis was performed on the 25 sub-indicators using SPSS. Finally, six principal components were extracted, and their coefficient weights of the explained total variance were 0.412, 0.184, 0.130, 0.120, 0.088, and 0.067, respectively. Table A1 shows the component score coefficient matrix. We use the formula F i = j = 1 J Z j S i j to calculate the total score for each component, where sij represents the score of component i for indicator j, zj represents the standardized value vector for indicator j, and N represents the number of indicators, which is 25. The formula H = i = 1 I W i F i is then used to obtain the original high-quality index, where Wi is the coefficient weight of the explained total variance for component i, I is the number of components, which is 6. Based on the needs of regression, the original high-quality index is standardized, that is, the original index is subtracted from the average value and divided by the difference between the maximum and minimum value. The standardized high-quality index is obtained, as shown in Table A2.
Table A1. Component score coefficient matrix.
Table A1. Component score coefficient matrix.
No.IndictorComp 1Comp 2Comp 3Comp 4Comp 5Comp 6
1Education level of residents0.115−0.0030.063−0.0120.0850.031
2Percentage of highly knowledgeable personnel0.113−0.0810.075−0.0390.0410.03
3Mechanized density0.060.0580.0650.207−0.330.200
4Mechanization development0.0370.050.0510.3860.037−0.145
5Economic growth rate−0.1030.0310.070.067−0.102−0.141
6Labor productivity−0.0070.1560.2470.0260.203−0.201
7Land output rate0.0540.1210.219−0.184−0.0860.152
8Irrigation area ratio0.096−0.030.1080.06−0.15−0.165
9Urban–rural income ratio0.0860.1220.0550.1370.221−0.069
10Urban–rural consumption ratio0.0570.0790.110.1730.310.192
11Degree of income balance0.105−0.102−0.11−0.10.0520.111
12Degree of consumption balance−0.1−0.002−0.0240.0370.0590.171
13Employment level−0.0570.145−0.2160.03−0.1150.174
14Industry structure−0.0980.0560.078−0.0530.043−0.169
15Fertilizer application intensity−0.056−0.159−0.0280.0990.2320.092
16Pesticide application intensity−0.045−0.190.030.1320.065−0.121
17Film usage intensity−0.0730.005−0.0740.0890.2430.128
18Carbon emission intensity0.026−0.1970.1010.012−0.0990.054
19Forest resources−0.0210.1530.116−0.2220.1340.305
20Arable land resources0.030.15−0.2810.130.041−0.068
21Road density0.080.101−0.227−0.0210.0530.106
22Foreign trade level0.0290.134−0.0450.033−0.243−0.202
23Electricity use per capita0.079−0.045−0.149−0.1310.176−0.143
24Medical resources distribution−0.02−0.0330.0760.178−0.1080.528
25Scale of medical resources0.087−0.09−0.0730.038−0.0010.086
Table A2. China’s provincial high-quality agricultural development index (2009–2019).
Table A2. China’s provincial high-quality agricultural development index (2009–2019).
Province20092010201120122013201420152016201720182019
Bei**g0.719 0.750 0.774 0.776 0.747 0.789 0.937 0.933 0.962 0.956 1.000
Tian**0.605 0.635 0.689 0.734 0.821 0.833 0.868 0.869 0.903 0.831 0.862
Hebei0.491 0.531 0.558 0.600 0.661 0.675 0.702 0.616 0.639 0.649 0.677
Shanxi0.375 0.398 0.429 0.499 0.538 0.546 0.601 0.510 0.501 0.516 0.525
Inner Mongolia0.334 0.330 0.365 0.426 0.508 0.540 0.582 0.591 0.586 0.612 0.659
Liaoning0.428 0.436 0.471 0.546 0.569 0.591 0.611 0.611 0.570 0.570 0.579
Jilin0.326 0.332 0.379 0.434 0.494 0.505 0.534 0.551 0.571 0.551 0.553
Heilongjiang0.300 0.318 0.384 0.436 0.455 0.495 0.522 0.548 0.558 0.580 0.636
Shanghai0.587 0.620 0.573 0.585 0.695 0.580 0.721 0.697 0.683 0.684 0.694
Jiangsu0.446 0.497 0.544 0.581 0.610 0.639 0.682 0.733 0.764 0.755 0.792
Zhejiang0.519 0.582 0.602 0.666 0.706 0.709 0.737 0.747 0.790 0.805 0.816
Anhui0.239 0.272 0.304 0.346 0.457 0.473 0.511 0.526 0.525 0.589 0.618
Fujian0.387 0.444 0.462 0.487 0.564 0.590 0.618 0.629 0.773 0.752 0.775
Jiangxi0.320 0.366 0.402 0.473 0.444 0.447 0.480 0.489 0.499 0.527 0.586
Shandong0.471 0.505 0.548 0.598 0.625 0.659 0.690 0.638 0.663 0.683 0.710
Henan0.335 0.373 0.402 0.426 0.478 0.532 0.551 0.550 0.580 0.614 0.667
Hubei0.275 0.325 0.355 0.419 0.515 0.530 0.583 0.601 0.628 0.656 0.669
Hunan0.297 0.336 0.346 0.408 0.469 0.487 0.531 0.549 0.575 0.573 0.612
Guangdong0.318 0.353 0.387 0.415 0.473 0.484 0.525 0.521 0.552 0.598 0.619
Guangxi0.149 0.187 0.214 0.255 0.329 0.379 0.406 0.428 0.460 0.463 0.510
Hainan0.255 0.311 0.348 0.403 0.469 0.492 0.543 0.601 0.687 0.715 0.751
Chongqing0.162 0.208 0.242 0.277 0.351 0.398 0.432 0.468 0.505 0.531 0.572
Sichuan0.171 0.177 0.195 0.264 0.340 0.352 0.382 0.388 0.437 0.473 0.507
Guizhou0.000 0.048 0.087 0.099 0.178 0.205 0.224 0.218 0.263 0.291 0.320
Yunnan0.027 0.079 0.081 0.138 0.167 0.191 0.227 0.243 0.279 0.274 0.323
Shaanxi0.229 0.266 0.295 0.344 0.410 0.421 0.466 0.451 0.483 0.514 0.509
Gansu0.108 0.151 0.181 0.220 0.282 0.294 0.317 0.274 0.320 0.318 0.316
Qinghai0.237 0.278 0.288 0.338 0.368 0.394 0.361 0.367 0.402 0.429 0.434
Ningxia0.198 0.226 0.244 0.284 0.341 0.345 0.380 0.350 0.417 0.390 0.394
**njiang0.228 0.296 0.309 0.349 0.396 0.429 0.411 0.408 0.448 0.445 0.452

References

  1. Zhou, S.; Mueller, F. Assessing Agricultural Sustainable Development Based on the DPSIR Approach: Case Study in Jiangsu, China. J. Integr. Agric. 2013, 12, 1292–1299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. OECD. OECD’s Producer Support Estimate and Relates Indicators of Agricultural Support: Concepts, Calculations, Interpretation and Use (the PSE Manual); OECD Publishing: Berlin, Germany, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  3. OECD. Agricultural Policy Monitoring and Evaluation 2020; OECD Publishing: Berlin, Germany, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  4. Guo, Y.; Tong, L. The effect of industrial agglomeration on green development efficiency in Northeast China since the revitalization. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 258, 120584. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Li, J.; Li, Y. Influence measurement of rapid urbanization on agricultural production factors based on provincial panel data. Socio-Econ. Plan. Sci. 2019, 67, 69–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Gang, F.; Ma, G. Marketisation in China from 1997 to 2014: Achievements and contribution to growth. In China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018; Australian National University Press: Canberra, Australia, 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Yu, Z. Agricultural Development Orientation Towards High Quality Stage. Zhongzhou J. Sci. 2018, 5, 40–44. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Zhang, H.; Zhang, J. Analysis of the threshold effect of agricultural industrial agglomeration and industrial structure upgrading on sustainable agricultural development in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 341, 130818. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Li, R.; Ma, Z.; Chen, X. Historical market genes, marketization and economic growth in China. Econ. Model. 2020, 86, 327–333. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Pan, W.; Wang, J.; Lu, Z.; Liu, Y. High-quality development in China: Measurement system, spatial pattern, and improvement paths. Habitat Int. 2021, 118, 102458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Zhong, Z.; Jiang, W.; Li, D. Can Socialized Services Promote the High-quality Development of Agriculture? An Empirical Analysis Based on the Grain Production Data of the Third National Agricultural Census. Chin. Rural. Econ. 2021, 12, 9–130. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  12. Havrylyshyn, O. Opening Up and Geographic Diversification of Trade in Transition Economies. IMF Work. Pap. 1998, 98, 22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. de Melo, M.; Cevdet, D.; Gelb, A. Patterns of Transition from Plan to Market. World Bank Econ. Rev. 1996, 10, 397–424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Yang, Y. Can the marketization of urban land transfer improve energy efficiency? J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 329, 117126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Margaret, M.; Samuel, K. Factors Determining Adoption of New Agricultural Technology by Smallholder Farmers in Devel-o** Countries. J. Econ. Sustain. Dev. 2015, 6, 5. [Google Scholar]
  16. Fan, G.; Wang, X.; Ma, G. Contribution of marketization to China’s economic growth. Econ. Res. J. 2011, 9, 1997–2011. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  17. Aghion, P.; Akcigit, U.; Howitt, P. What do we learn from Schumpeterian growth theory? Handb. Econ. Growth 2014, 2, 515–563. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Iradian, G. What explains the rapid growth in transition economies? IMF Staff. Pap. 2009, 56, 4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Magruder, J.R. An Assessment of Experimental Evidence on Agricultural Technology Adoption in Develo** Countries. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 2018, 10, 299–316. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Doucouliagos, C.; Ulubasoglu, M.A. Economic freedom and economic growth: Does specification make a difference? Eur. J. Political Econ. 2006, 22, 1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Fu, F. Building an open and stable capital market: A supervision intensity perspective. J. Asia Pac. Econ. 2022, 27, 3. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Guang, H.W.; Enjiang, C. Effects of land fragmentation and returns to scale in the Chinese farming sector. Appl. Econ. 2001, 33, 2. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Terry, D. Scenarios of Central European land fragmentation. Land Use Policy 2003, 20, 2. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Martinez, M.; Mlachila, M. The Quality of the Recent High-Growth Episode in Sub-Saharan Africa. IMF Work. Pap. 2013, 13, 53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Brown, L. The Development of Chinese; Norton & Company: New York, NY, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  26. King, F.H. Farmers of Forty Centuries. Small Farmer’s J. 2009, 3, 33. [Google Scholar]
  27. Liang, S.; Yu, Z. Evaluation and Countermeasures of the Agricultural Development Potential of China’s Water Resources. Agric. Econ. Issues 2016, 9, 10. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Kirtti, R.P.; Phanindra, G. Impact of farmer education on farm productivity under varying technologies: Case of paddy grow-ers in India. Agric. Food Econ. 2018, 6, 7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Zhang, M.; Du, P.; Jiang, L. Impact of endogenous power factors and price marketization on agricultural energy efficiency: Based on the use of coal and oil energy in China. Resour. Policy 2023, 83, 103653. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Zhong, W.; Zheng, M. How the Marketization of Land Transfer Affects High-Quality Economic Development: Empirical Evidence from 284 Prefecture-Level Cities in China. Sustainability 2022, 14, 12639. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Yao, W.; Wang, C. Agricultural land marketization and productivity: Evidence from China. J. Appl. Econ. 2022, 25, 1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Tongwei, Q.; Luo, B.; Choy, S.T.B.; Li, Y.; He, Q. Do land renting-in and its marketization increase labor input in agriculture? Evidence from rural China. Land Use Policy 2020, 99, 104820. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Francesco, C.; Nicola, G. Credit Constraints, Competition, and Meritocracy. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2005, 3, 2. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Hsieh, C.T.; Klenow, P.J. Development accounting. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 2010, 2, 207–223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Elizabeth, B. Winners and Losers in Russia’s Economic Transition. Am. Econ. Rev. 1998, 88, 1094–1116. [Google Scholar]
  36. Chang, T.H.; Zheng, S. Grasp the Large, Let Go of the Small: The Transformation of the State Sector in China. Brook. Pap. Econ. Act. 2016, 2015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Joko, M. Farmer training to simultaneously increase productivity of soybean and rice in Indonesia. Int. J. Product. Perform. Manag. 2019, 68, 6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Carvalho, F.P. Pesticides, environment, and food safety. Food Energy Secur. 2017, 6, 2. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Jiang, X.; Lu, X.; Gong, M. Assessing the effects of land transfer marketization on green total factor productivity from the perspective of resource allocation: Evidence from China. Front. Environ. Sci. 2022, 10, 975282. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Huang, X. Index Construction and Evaluation of High-quality Development of Agriculture in China. Chin. J. Agric. Resour. Reg. Plan. 2020, 4, 124. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  41. Hao, X. Considerations about Actively Promoting China’s Agricultural High-quality Development. North. Forum 2019, 3, 8–14. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  42. Satter, D. Yeltsin: Shadow of a Doubt. Natl. Interest 1993, 34, 52–57. [Google Scholar]
  43. Bose, P.; Luciana, E. Corruption with Heterogeneous Enforcement Agents in the Shadow Economy. JITE 2007, 2, 285–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Aschauer, D.A. Is public expenditure productive? J. Monet. Econ. 1989, 23, 177–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Evans, P.; Karras, G. Is government capital productive? Evidence from a panel of seven countries. J. Macroecon. 1994, 16, 271–279. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Kneller, R.; Bleaney, M.F.; Gemmell, N. Fiscal policy and growth: Evidence from OECD countries. J. Public Econ. 1999, 74, 171–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Landau, D. Government Expenditure and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Study. South. Econ. J. 1983, 3, 783–792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Landau, D. Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study for 1960–1980. Econ. Dev. Cult. Chang. 1986, 1, 35–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Devarajan, S.; Swaroop, V.; Hengfu, Z. The composition of public expenditure and economic growth. J. Monet. Econ. 1996, 37, 313–344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  50. Arawatari, R.; Hori, T.; Mino, K. Government expenditure and economic growth: A heterogeneous-agents approach. J. Macroecon. 2023, 75, 103486. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Child, J.; Tse, D.K. Chinas Transition and its Implications for International Business. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 2001, 32, 5–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Liu, X.; **, L.; Jie, Y.; Jian, Z.; Kangli, L. Spatiotemporal assessment of land marketization and its driving forces for sustainable urban–rural development in Shaanxi province in China. Sustainability 2021, 13, 7755. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Nawab, K.; Ram, L.R.; Hazem, S.K.; Sajjad, H.; Shemei, Z.; Muhammad, K.M. Potential role of technology innovation in transformation of sustainable food systems: A review. Agriculture 2021, 11, 984. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Dayana, A.; Felipe, P.; Fabio, R.S. Syntropy and innovation in agriculture. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain. 2020, 45, 20–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Kyle, E.; Alain, D.J.; Elisabeth, S.; Manzoor, H. Technological innovations, downside risk, and the modernization of agriculture. Am. Econ. Rev. 2016, 106, 1537–1561. [Google Scholar]
  56. Emma, J.; Simon, F.; Aysha, F.; Cara, S. Reflecting on opportunities and challenges regarding implementation of responsible digital agri-technology innovation. Sociol. Rural. 2022, 62, 363–388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Ugonna, B.F. Knowledge and skills for accessing agricultural information by rural farmers in South-East Nigeria. IFLA J. 2021, 47, 119–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Mishuk, P.S.; Kabir, M.H.; Alam, M. Assessing the Effectiveness of Department of Agricultural Extension (DAE) Services to Increase Farmers’ Skill. Asian J. Agric. Ext. Econ. Sociol. 2021, 39, 68–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Tamsah, H.; Yusriadi, Y. Quality of agricultural extension on productivity of farmers: Human capital perspective. Uncertain Supply Chain. Manag. 2022, 10, 625–636. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Rong, H.; Chaofeng, S.; Rongguang, S.; Zheyu, Z.; Run, Z. Development trend and driving factors of agricultural chemical fertilizer efficiency in China. Sustainability 2020, 12, 4607. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Guo, L.; Zhao, S.; Song, Y.; Tang, M.; Li, H. Green finance, chemical fertilizer use and carbon emissions from agricultural production. Agriculture 2022, 12, 313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Shuqin, J.; Fang, Z. Zero growth of chemical fertilizer and pesticide use: China’s objectives, progress and challenges. J. Resour. Ecol. 2018, 9, 50–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Liu, Y. The Reform and Development of Non-state-owned Economy in China in the Past 30 Years: Achievements, Experience and Prospect. Econ. Manag. Stud. 2019, 1, 29. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  64. Liu, W. The Ownership Change and the Economic Growth and Upgrading of Factors Efficiency. Econ. Res. 2001, 1. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  65. **, W.; Zhou, C. Effect of Land Marketization Level and Land Prices on Foreign Direct Investment in China. Land 2022, 11, 1433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Lili, G.; Dianshuang, W. Factor Market Distortions, Agricultural Producer Service and Agricultural Productivity. Asian J. Econ. Bus. Account. 2022, 22, 15–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Temporal trend and provincial differences in China’s high-quality agricultural development index.
Figure 1. Temporal trend and provincial differences in China’s high-quality agricultural development index.
Sustainability 15 09498 g001
Figure 2. Kernel density distribution of the high-quality index. Note: In order to display the result more clearly, the years 2009, 2014, and 2019 were selected for investigation in this paper.
Figure 2. Kernel density distribution of the high-quality index. Note: In order to display the result more clearly, the years 2009, 2014, and 2019 were selected for investigation in this paper.
Sustainability 15 09498 g002
Figure 3. QAP regression coefficients (without control variables).
Figure 3. QAP regression coefficients (without control variables).
Sustainability 15 09498 g003
Figure 4. QAP regression coefficients (with control variables).
Figure 4. QAP regression coefficients (with control variables).
Sustainability 15 09498 g004
Table 1. Agricultural quality development index.
Table 1. Agricultural quality development index.
GuidelinesElementsIndicatorsIndicator CalculationPropertiesWeight
InnovationInnovation foundationEducation level of residentsNumber of years of education per inhabitant over 15 years old+0.063
Percentage of highly knowledgeable personnelPercentage of population aged 15 and above with college education+0.042
Mechanized densityTotal machinery power/sown crop area+0.053
Mechanization developmentTotal mechanical power/number of people employed in the primary sector+0.071
Innovation performanceEconomic growth rateAnnual growth rate of added value from agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, and fishery+0.038
Labor productivityValue added from agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, and fishery/total rural population+0.065
Land output rateValue added from agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, and fishery/ sown crop area+0.053
Irrigation area ratioIrrigated area/sown crop area+0.031
CoordinationPeople’s livelihoodUrban–rural income ratioUrban per capita income/rural per capita income0.096
Urban–rural consumption ratioUrban per capita consumption/rural per capita consumption0.113
Degree of income balanceRural per capita income /GDP per capita+0.010
Degree of consumption balanceRural per capita consumption/GDP per capita+0.024
Industry developmentEmployment levelNumber of people employed in primary industry+0.020
Industry structureValue added from agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, and fishery/GDP+0.034
GreennessEnvironmental protectionFertilizer application intensityFertilizer application/sown crop area0.018
Pesticide application intensityPesticide application/sown crop area0.036
Film usage intensityAmount of agricultural film used/sown crop area0.002
Carbon emission intensityCarbon emissions from the agricultural sector0.016
Resource conservationForest resourcesForest cover+0.040
Arable land resourcesSown crop area/total area of the region+0.018
OpeningInfrastructureRoad densityNumber of road miles/total area of the region+0.031
Market developmentForeign trade levelTotal import and export of agricultural products/GDP+0.001
SharingStandard of livingElectricity use per capitaRural electricity consumption/rural population+0.005
Public servicesMedical resources distributionAverage number of staff per village health office+0.043
Scale of medical resourcesAverage number of rural doctors and health care workers per 1000 people in the agricultural population+0.020
Note: A positive sign in the attribute column indicates that the indicator value is positively correlated with the value of the agricultural quality development index, and the higher the indicator value, the higher the level of agricultural quality development; a negative sign indicates that the indicator value is negatively correlated with the value of agricultural quality development index, and the higher the indicator value, the lower the level of agricultural quality development. The last column is the weight coefficients from the principal component analysis in Section 4.1, which can measure the correlation between a sub-indicator and the agricultural high-quality index, and the greater the weight, the stronger the correlation.
Table 2. Dagum’s Gini coefficient and its decomposition results for the agricultural high-quality development index.
Table 2. Dagum’s Gini coefficient and its decomposition results for the agricultural high-quality development index.
Total Gini CoefficientIntra-Regional Gini CoefficientInter-Regional Gini CoefficientContribution Rate %
EastCentralWestEast-CentralEast-WestCentral-WestIntra-RegionInter-RegionSuper Variable Density
20090.2860.1490.0680.3020.2280.4800.30719.60478.2622.133
20100.2540.1340.0590.2320.2130.4320.25318.94579.8951.158
20110.2370.1210.0540.2080.1890.4080.24918.38380.5121.103
20120.2100.1080.0520.1840.1590.3620.22818.70379.7431.552
20130.1790.0940.0340.1510.1400.3090.18818.49579.9261.577
20140.1660.0910.0340.1450.1270.2830.17419.4578.5342.008
20150.1700.0940.0370.1390.1300.2920.18118.952379.2521.795
20160.1690.0910.0300.1510.1250.2900.18319.20979.1281.662
20170.1590.0940.0410.1240.1370.2690.14719.68778.8891.422
20180.150.0800.0410.1310.1200.2560.15119.70078.6201.679
20190.1480.0820.0440.1300.1130.2480.15520.31677.102.575
Table 3. Regression of total indicators for the full sample.
Table 3. Regression of total indicators for the full sample.
Model VariablesModel I (No Control Variables)Model II (with Control Variables)
Unstandardized CoefficientStandardization Factorp-ValueplargepsmallUnstandardized CoefficientStandardization Factorp-Valueplargepsmall
Intercept distance0.2060.0000.0000.0000.000−0.7910.0000.0000.0000.000
Marketization index0.0940.4640.0010.0011.0000.0450.2250.0030.0030.997
Industry structure 0.0480.1120.1440.1440.856
Urbanization rate 0.0120.4310.0010.0011.000
Old age dependency ratio −0.013−0.0870.1090.8920.109
Geographical distance 0.0680.1350.0210.0210.980
Adj.R20.215 (0.000)0.440 (0.000)
Number of observations870870
Note: All variables are 30 × 30 matrices with 0 main diagonal elements, so the number of sample observations is 30 × (30 − 1) = 870. There were a total of 2000 random permutations. plarge denotes the proportion of random permutations producing regression coefficients greater than or equal to the long vector regression coefficients; psmall denotes the proportion of random permutations producing regression coefficients less than or equal to the long vector regression coefficients. The values in parentheses for Adj.R2 are p-values, i.e., the proportion of random permutations with R2 greater than or equal to the long vector regression R2 to the total number of random permutations. The significance of the regression coefficients is tested using a two-tailed test, and the significance level is indicated using plarge when the regression coefficients are positive and using psmall otherwise.
Table 4. Full sample sub-indicator regression.
Table 4. Full sample sub-indicator regression.
Model VariablesModel I (No Control Variables)Model II (with Control Variables)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)
Intercept distance0.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.000
(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)(0.000)
1. The degree of governmental regulation of the economy.0.212 ** 0.068
(0.023) (0.019)
2. Non-state-owned economic development. 0.243 ** 0.213 ***
(0.017) (0.013)
3. Product market development. 0.113 0.053
(0.029) (0.025)
4. Factor market development. 0.544 *** 0.177 **
(0.017) (0.017)
5. Market level of order. 0.476 *** 0.201 **
(0.008) (0.008)
Industry structure 0.0950.1100.0610.0350.083
(0.050)(0.048)(0.051)(0.049)(0.048)
Urbanization rate 0.537 ***0.541 ***0.568 ***0.445 ***0.442 ***
(0.003)(0.003)(0.003)(0.003)(0.003)
Old age dependency ratio −0.055−0.052−0.047−0.056−0.065
(0.011)(0.010)(0.011)(0.011)(0.010)
Geographical distance 0.164 ***0.115 **0.173 ***0.178 ***0.183 ***
(0.034)(0.034)(0.036)(0.035)(0.034)
Adj. R20.044 **0.056 **0.0120.296 ***0.225 ***0.408 ***0.444 ***0.407 ***0.416 ***0.431 ***
Number of observations870870870870870870870870870870
Note: *** and ** indicate significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses.
Table 5. Regression by period.
Table 5. Regression by period.
No Control VariablesWith Control Variables
Pre-PhaseLate StagePre-PhaseLate Stage
Marketization index0.396 ***0.491 ***0.111 *0.316 ***
(0.019)(0.016)(0.018)(0.015)
Sub-indicators1. The degree of governmental regulation of the economy.0.163 *0.205 **0.0100.085
(0.022)(0.023)(0.018)(0.018)
2. Non-state-owned economic development.0.164 *0.327 ***0.131 **0.301 ***
(0.016)(0.018)(0.013)(0.014)
3. Product market development.0.0640.177 *0.0100.099
(0.030)(0.025)(0.025)(0.022)
4. Factor market development.0.433 ***0.522 ***−0.0670.267 ***
(0.020)(0.012)(0.020)(0.011)
5. Market level of order.0.402 ***0.516 ***0.0920.295 ***
(0.010)(0.007)(0.009)(0.007)
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses. For the pre-phase columns, the data from 2009 to 2014 are used for regression, while for the late-stage columns, data from 2015 to 2019 are used.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Qi, Y.; Gao, M.; Wang, H.; Ding, H.; Liu, J.; Sriboonchitta, S. Does Marketization Promote High-Quality Agricultural Development in China? Sustainability 2023, 15, 9498. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15129498

AMA Style

Qi Y, Gao M, Wang H, Ding H, Liu J, Sriboonchitta S. Does Marketization Promote High-Quality Agricultural Development in China? Sustainability. 2023; 15(12):9498. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15129498

Chicago/Turabian Style

Qi, Yang, Mingyue Gao, Haoyu Wang, Huijie Ding, Jianxu Liu, and Songsak Sriboonchitta. 2023. "Does Marketization Promote High-Quality Agricultural Development in China?" Sustainability 15, no. 12: 9498. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15129498

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop